
Tort reform.
Both words would seem to require some definition for all but those steeped in
the movement to achieve tort reform and those fervently fighting to preserve
the status quo.
So
what is a “tort?” The word itself derives from the 11th-century
Latin word tortum, meaning injustice,
tortum springing from the Latin word tortus, meaning twisted. Tortus comes from the Latin word torquere, meaning to turn awry or wring.
In American legal parlance, tort means “a wrongful act or an infringement of a
right leading to civil legal liability.” Modernly, tort law is thought of as
“personal injury” law.[i] Tort law has been a part
of the American legal fabric since the United States’ establishment, having
been adopted as a part of the British common-law system.
And so
– in the legal and political senses – what does “reform” mean? When
legislative bodies want to enact legislation altering a legal construct like
tort law, they quite often title the bill that way, e.g. (here, hypothetically), the “Tort Reform Act of 2017.” The
fact of the word “reform” being in the title of the bill allows it proponents
the opportunity to presume that reform is needed or necessary. Its opponents, ,
would argue that the use of the term is clearly presumptuous as, in their view,
the construct needs no reformation at all (or perhaps only the slightest
amount); in fact, many of them call this movement “tort deform” instead.
The
tort-reform movement has been in existence for many years. Its development comes
from industries that are on the receiving end of tort suits, e.g., medical malpractice lawsuits, and
the insurance industry, which pays the vast majority of the costs when a
personal injury results in liability and judgment. Personal injury lawsuits, as
with virtually all civil lawsuits, have two principal components: liability and
damages. First, liability must be shown; that is, that a duty existed and that
the duty was breached, meaning the duty of one person not to physically harm
another person accompanied by actual injury. Second, to recover damages, it is
not enough that liability be shown; there also must be compensable damages
suffered by the injured party. A simple example would be where party A’s
automobile collides with the automobile of party B. Party A had a duty not to
unreasonably strike Party B who was acting reasonably (liability). The
collision resulted in Party B suffering damages to his automobile and a broken
arm. Party A must compensate Party B for the property damages and the medical
bills for the broken arm (damages).
There
are many types of personal injuries, of course, from the common one just
described to such as the highly complex and long-running mass-tort litigation
relating to asbestos. In the 1920s, medical science began to conclude that
working around asbestos could lead to asbestosis, mesothelioma, and other forms
of cancer. Lawsuits from workers afflicted with asbestos-related diseases were
filed, culminating in thousands of such cases coming to be associated with the multi-district
litigation that has been headquartered in a Pennsylvania federal district court
for decades now and which is still ongoing. Damage awards, settlements, and
funds set aside by corporations and insurance companies for asbestos victims
have amounted to multiple billions of dollars.
The
vast majority of routine tort claims are not frivolous and do not result in
mega-verdicts by juries, but tort-reform proponents – mostly the largest
corporations in general, those who support them, e.g., chamber of commerce-type organizations, politically
conservative individuals, and Republican-controlled legislatures – believe
there is a long-running problem with tort claims. These perceived problems take
on a variety of forms. First, there are those who believe that certain types of
tort lawsuits ought not be allowed to even be filed or at least should have
serious restrictions, an example being restrictions placed on the filing and
conduct of medical malpractice suits by some state legislatures.[ii] Mostly, however, it is
not the number of lawsuits filedor even rulings declaring liability that prompt
calls for reform from tort-reform proponents. Rather, it is the amount of
damages that are awarded by judges and
juries where there are no legislatively-imposed limitations.
In
other words, tort reform is about money. In the view of tort-reform proponents,
the filing of “frivolous” tort claims and “excessive” jury awards adversely
harm business interests and the economy by causing fewer business start-ups and
by causing business failures, thus depriving the economy of new and existing
jobs. Tort-reform proponents argue that these lawsuits drive up the cost of
insurance premiums and other costs for businesses and professionals having to
defend themselves against “unwarranted” claims resulting in “huge” damage
awards. As a result, would be entrepreneurs and business owners become hesitant
to establish businesses and potentially expose themselves to tort liability.
In
2014, Republicans gained control of the U.S. Senate. With the election of
Donald Trump as President in 2016, a
Republican President is in the White House. And while there has been much talk
in Congress of tort reform, so far it has been only talk as no tort-reform
measure has been enacted.
That
is decidedly not the case in state
legislatures, however. Most of the states passed some form of tort-reform
legislation in the 1980s. The clamor continues to end frivolous tort lawsuits
by capping certain forms of damages and by other measures.
Opponents
of tort reform, on the other hand, argue that there is no reliable empirical
evidence that the tort “reforms” that have been enacted over the last several
decades have achieved any laudable purpose, such as creating and retaining jobs
or significantly reducing costs. The opponents argue that the tort reforms
efforts has allowed large companies to
reap huge profits on the backs of injured persons. For example, opponents argue
that corporations are not devoting as many resources to safety and injury
prevention because under tort reform it is cheaper for corporations to be less
cognizant of safety and simply pay the capped jury awards that come along once
in a while. The arguments on both sides are meritorious. For tort reform
advocates, there have been abuses of the system, both in the context of the
filing of marginal, and even frivolous, cases and in the context of jury awards
approved by judges that clearly were grossly excessive in the circumstances
(most of the time, such awards are overturned or significantly reduced by
appellate courts). There have been clear examples of abuses by corporations in
the context of knowingly committing torts. A third front has emerged,
suggesting that while some tort reform may be a good thing, the present reform
ideas are ill-conceived and that reasonable compromise would be a much better
idea.
By no
means is the battle over. As Republicans gain control of more state
legislatures, more tort reform legislation is proposed. The current situation
in Arkansas is an instructive example. In 2017, the Arkansas General Assembly
placed a proposed constitutional amendment on the next general election ballot
that will limit the contingency fees[iii] that lawyers can charge their
clients in tort cases and place hard caps on both punitive[iv] and non-economic[v] damages.
Max
Brantly recently wrote in the Arkansas Times: “The trial lawyers [and
Democrats] will spend plenty [in an attempt] to stop what amounts to stripping
the Arkansas Constitution of the right to a jury trial for damages. But
perverse Arkansas – though no home to runaway juries or financially-strained
nursing-home owners or doctors – is inclined to buy propositions that the
chamber of commerce declares good for business. If being hospitable to business
and inhospitable to workers was a ticket to economic glory land, Arkansas would
be Silicon Valley, the Research Triangle, and the Johnson Space Center rolled
into one.”[vi]
The
arguments rage on. To tort-reform proponents, it is an economic and fairness
argument. To tort-reform opponents, it is a human and fairness argument,
meaning why should a legislature pre-impose arbitrary and subjective
limitations on damages suffered by particular individuals it knows nothing
about? Due to the inherent complexities of this argument, it will not be
settled any time soon.
[i] While tort law can involve an injury to business rather than person, this
article will involve tort law only as it relates to personal injury. The terms
“tort” and “personal injury” are used interchangeably in this article.
[ii] In Texas, there are many
legislatively-imposed restrictions on medical malpractice actions.
[iii] Contingency fees constitute a
percentage of the recovery in behalf of a client being paid to the lawyer,
often 40% or more. While many criticize the contingency-fee system, the simple
truth is that, but for such a system, most individuals would be financially
unable even to file, much less prosecute, a tort claim.
[iv] Punitive damages are a highly
controversial form of damages. It is these damages that tort-reform proponents
dislike the most because they are not directly connected to any damages
suffered by a tort victim; rather, they are meant to punish the entity
committing the tort for its conduct and offer an incentive not to engage in
such behavior again. That these damages are awarded to the tort victim seems
wrong to tort-reform proponents. Generally, they are awarded only in the most
egregious of cases.
[v] Damages such as pain and suffering.
[vi] Max
Brantley, “You Want Tort Reform? Try This.,” Arkansas Times, https://www.arktimes.com/arkansas/you-want-tort-reform-try-this/Content?oid=6824189.